Kevin's Reviews > The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era: Primitive Accumulation and the Peasantry
The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era: Primitive Accumulation and the Peasantry
by
by

Kevin's review
bookshelves: environment-agriculture, econ-imperialism, 1-how-the-world-works, econ-resources, econ-land, critique-imperialism-europe, econ-inequality, econ-development, 2-brilliant-intros-101, history-origin-capitalism, history-industrial-revolution, history-africa, history-europe, history-europe-imperialism, history-asia-india
Dec 17, 2021
bookshelves: environment-agriculture, econ-imperialism, 1-how-the-world-works, econ-resources, econ-land, critique-imperialism-europe, econ-inequality, econ-development, 2-brilliant-intros-101, history-origin-capitalism, history-industrial-revolution, history-africa, history-europe, history-europe-imperialism, history-asia-india
Economics of Imperialism 101
Preamble:
--2021 has been a year where I decided to check off as many intimidating-but-must-reads as possible, from Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1 to Michael Hudson tomes (Super Imperialism: The Origin and Fundamentals of U.S. World Dominance and The Bubble and Beyond). Along the way, there were several unexpected gems (ex. Jason Hickel's Less is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World and The Divide: A Brief Guide to Global Inequality and its Solutions).
...So, it is quite something that this 96-pager stood out.
--First, consider the lineage of (Western) “E³¦´Ç²Ô´Ç³¾¾±³¦²õâ€�:
1) Classical trade theory was conveniently imperialist as capitalist industrialization was predicated on colonialism’s cheap (often tropical) inputs + labour.
2) Marx critiqued Classical economics, but never lived long enough to get to their trade theory, derailing many Western Marxists.
3) Mainstream economics (Neoclassical), horrified by Marx using Classical economics to critique capitalism, rejected Classical along with reality.
4) John Maynard Keynes, in critiquing Neoclassical fantasies during the Great Depression, still represented the British Empire.
…So, I’m not being a jackass when I give 2-stars to:
1) Your Western capitalism-reformer heroes: Paul Krugman, Joseph E. Stiglitz, Thomas Piketty... at their best with Mariana Mazzucato's Mission Economy: A Moonshot Guide to Changing Capitalism.
2) Global South reformists like Ha-Joon Chang (Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism), Amartya Sen (Development as Freedom), etc.
...If it’s any consolation, I try to be just as critical of Western scholars I look up to when they make such omissions, ex. Michael Hudson's Killing the Host: How Financial Parasites and Debt Bondage Destroy the Global Economy and David Harvey's A Brief History of Neoliberalism.
--To be taken seriously, critical Global South economists trying to synthesize imperialism must work their way backwards through this mountain of biased, self-referential assumptions accumulating over centuries; this also means that success in this challenge completely flips “E³¦´Ç²Ô´Ç³¾¾±³¦²õâ€� on its head!
--I was lucky to stumble across Vijay Prashad some 8 years ago, who flipped geopolitics/history on its head by opening the door to anti-imperialist Global South perspectives (). Vijay mentioned Prabhat Patnaik as his favorite economist. No doubt Prabhat is a treasure, but his delivery is steeped in labyrinthian economic theory.
…I could not distinguish this in Prabhat’s co-authored books theorizing imperialism, but it turns out the other half of the Patnaik power couple is more decipherable in presentation; this makes Utsa Patnaik the dream radical economist! Have a listen:
Highlights:
1) Western Financial Crises or Imperialist Agrarian Crises?:
--First, note that we should avoid being crude/sectarian. I’m not setting up a bipolar “either or� scenario here, as clearly both factors are present and interact with each other. I am merely contrasting the two to demonstrate the overwhelming bias that one perspective enjoys in both mainstream and alternative economics.
--(Western) Economics� conception of economic crises revolve around Western Finance:
a) Great Depression:
--Economics� focus is on the 1929 Great Crash of Wall Street, as well as the preceding “Roaring Twenties� (1920s) of mass consumer industrial production and financial speculation.
--Utsa instead focuses on agricultural production, i.e. food and certain primary commodities (raw material inputs to industry; Utsa seems less focused on energy here). WWI disrupted European agriculture, resulting in an expansion of agricultural output outside Europe. By post-WWI recovery, there was agricultural overproduction relative to demand, resulting in a severe and prolonged fall in global agricultural prices starting in 1924-25. This disrupted the trade balances of exporters; the pre-Keynesian economic response was national austerity. The resulting global demand downward spiral hit late-industrializing Germany/Italy/Japan, who (typical for capitalist crises) reacted with fascism: military production to revive demand and expansionism to seize raw materials.
--Next steps: synthesize Michael Hudson’s geopolitical economy (mostly starting from Western perspectives, Super Imperialism: The Origin and Fundamentals of U.S. World Dominance and Trade, Development and Foreign Debt) with the Patnaiks' Global South version (for their magnum opus, see Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History, and the Present).
b) Neoliberalism:
--Economics focuses on the Western stagflation crisis (unemployment + inflation) and generally blame this on labour unions and social welfare spending. Those who actually consider reality focus on the geopolitics of US’s post-WWII Bretton Woods global plan, and how it was disrupted by US genocidal war spendings in Korea and Vietnam (Hudson's aforementioned Super Imperialism and Varoufakis' The Global Minotaur: America, the True Origins of the Financial Crisis and the Future of the World Economy).
--The bridge to Global South perspectives starts with the 1973 and 1979 Oil Shocks. Note: Hudson contextualizes the Oil Shocks with a prior grain embargo by the US quadrupling grain prices (I’ll have to dig on this and how it relates with the mainstream rendition of the “Great Grain Robbery� of 1972 from USSR purchasing US grain).
--The broader Global South context is decolonization in the 1950-60s, thus de-linking of Global South developmental states away from global capitalism’s imperialist Finance/trade dependency in order to build national food sovereignty. Western “Leftists� with their heads in the clouds of Capitalist Realism: Is There No Alternative? cannot seem to empathize with this period of social change and imagination: The Darker Nations: A People's History of the Third World.
--This national de-linking and internationalist decolonization (symbolized by the push for the New International Economic Order, NIEO, to challenge colonial-era commodity pricing, finance, and technologies) was of course an existential threat to global capitalism, which responded by unleashing Finance (“Financialization�; Wall Street had been regulated after the Great Crash and during the post-WWII “Golden Age� after all) and reviving imperialist onslaughts (IMF/World Bank “Structural Adjustment Programs�). Note: Hudson stresses the US/World Bank global plan is for the US to control the global food supply (i.e. food staples) with its intensive industrial + heavily-subsidized agriculture, while the Global South exports cash crops.
c) Today’s Late-Neoliberalism:
--Since “Neoliberalism� unleashed Wall Street, there has been much to say on Financial crises (including 2008). Utsa considers the growing demand for Global South agriculture via air-freighting of perishable products alongside Neoliberalism’s destruction of postcolonial states� food sovereignty policies. Ex. India’s infamous farmer suicides starting from Neoliberal onslaughts in the 1990s, where peasant farmers must now contend with volatile global food prices (including Financial speculation), multinational corporate expansion and financial rent-seeking, all without the developmental state’s protection.
2) Western Agricultural Revolution or Free Trade Imperialism?:
--Utsa challenges the nation-by-nation narratives (which conveniently obscures imperialism) where the West supposedly went through the Industrial Revolution thanks to first completing an Agricultural Revolution into capitalist agriculture, thus generating the surpluses required for industrial inputs and wage-income consumer demands.
--Utsa rejects W. Arthur Lewis� narrative comparing Great Britain’s supposedly superior agricultural productivity by pointing out the time variable is omitted. Western Europe has 1 growing season vs. the tropical Global South’s 2-3 crops in a year. Medieval Europe was barren even for elites compared to tropical biodiversity. Indeed, the period of intense European industrialization was marked by domestic bread riots, demonstrating the lack of a successful “Agricultural Revolution� and the reliance on Ireland and tropical colonies.
--Utsa rejects Ricardo’s “Comparative Advantage� (where both countries can benefit from trade if they specialize on what is most cost-efficient for themselves, even if one country is more cost-efficient in producing both goods), the centerpiece of Classical trade theory (and adopted by Neoclassical); the material fallacy made is that both countries can produce all goods and simply chooses the most cost-efficient option. This is convenient for free trade imperialism in convincing the Global South (rich in biodiversity) that it is they who are poor and must specialize in exporting exotic cash crops to keep Global North supermarkets well-stocked for all seasons (not to mention crucial industrial inputs), giving up their food sovereignty and relying on the Global North’s heavily industrialized/subsidized agriculture for food staples (grain)!
--A final myth obscuring increased poverty in the Global South is the idea that a decline in cereal crop output is a good sign showing progress in the modernization of diets (more meat/dairy). Meat/dairy are actually a huge drain on food/energy inputs as they require significant cereal crop as livestock feed, diverting this from direct consumption.
Next Steps:
--Part of this book’s appeal is its concise (96 pages) presentation of systemic concepts. Thus, much is missing; I’ve tried to fill in some key contextual points above to demonstrate just how much contrast is created with this anti-imperialist paradigm.
--Note: Sam Moyo wrote the second (smaller) half of the book, with African examples to match Utsa’s economic framework (with more focus on land tenure property relations). Moyo’s style is a bit closer to a history textbook (more places/names rather than economic structures) reminiscent of How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, which I personally find less revelatory (esp. applied to an entire continent in 20 pages).
--Related topics that require many more pages to unpack:
1) Green Revolution: I know Vandana Shiva’s critiques are popular here, but I’m looking for more systems-level critiques. I believe Michael Perelman did his PhD on this: Farming For Profit In A Hungry World: Capital And The Crisis In Agriculture. The critique in A People’s Green New Deal is very compelling.
2) Famines: along with “gulags�, this is the popular fear-mongering against “socialism�. Here, Utsa is crucial as she both details the greatest famine conveniently ignored by the West (Bengal Famine of 1943), and challenges the famine research on communist China even beyond “Nobel� Economics Prize winner Amartya Sen and Drèze’s famous comparison of hunger in communist China vs. capitalist India in Hunger and Public Action (I review both Utsa’s critique and Sen/Drèze in this linked review).
3) Capitalism and Imperialism, mapping out the structural phases throughout history, where Utsa is joined by Prabhat Patnaik:
-overview: The Veins of the South Are Still Open: Debates Around the Imperialism of Our Time
-theory (+ debate with Harvey!): A Theory of Imperialism
-theory + history: Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History, and the Present
Preamble:
--2021 has been a year where I decided to check off as many intimidating-but-must-reads as possible, from Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1 to Michael Hudson tomes (Super Imperialism: The Origin and Fundamentals of U.S. World Dominance and The Bubble and Beyond). Along the way, there were several unexpected gems (ex. Jason Hickel's Less is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World and The Divide: A Brief Guide to Global Inequality and its Solutions).
...So, it is quite something that this 96-pager stood out.
--First, consider the lineage of (Western) “E³¦´Ç²Ô´Ç³¾¾±³¦²õâ€�:
1) Classical trade theory was conveniently imperialist as capitalist industrialization was predicated on colonialism’s cheap (often tropical) inputs + labour.
2) Marx critiqued Classical economics, but never lived long enough to get to their trade theory, derailing many Western Marxists.
3) Mainstream economics (Neoclassical), horrified by Marx using Classical economics to critique capitalism, rejected Classical along with reality.
4) John Maynard Keynes, in critiquing Neoclassical fantasies during the Great Depression, still represented the British Empire.
…So, I’m not being a jackass when I give 2-stars to:
1) Your Western capitalism-reformer heroes: Paul Krugman, Joseph E. Stiglitz, Thomas Piketty... at their best with Mariana Mazzucato's Mission Economy: A Moonshot Guide to Changing Capitalism.
2) Global South reformists like Ha-Joon Chang (Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism), Amartya Sen (Development as Freedom), etc.
...If it’s any consolation, I try to be just as critical of Western scholars I look up to when they make such omissions, ex. Michael Hudson's Killing the Host: How Financial Parasites and Debt Bondage Destroy the Global Economy and David Harvey's A Brief History of Neoliberalism.
--To be taken seriously, critical Global South economists trying to synthesize imperialism must work their way backwards through this mountain of biased, self-referential assumptions accumulating over centuries; this also means that success in this challenge completely flips “E³¦´Ç²Ô´Ç³¾¾±³¦²õâ€� on its head!
--I was lucky to stumble across Vijay Prashad some 8 years ago, who flipped geopolitics/history on its head by opening the door to anti-imperialist Global South perspectives (). Vijay mentioned Prabhat Patnaik as his favorite economist. No doubt Prabhat is a treasure, but his delivery is steeped in labyrinthian economic theory.
…I could not distinguish this in Prabhat’s co-authored books theorizing imperialism, but it turns out the other half of the Patnaik power couple is more decipherable in presentation; this makes Utsa Patnaik the dream radical economist! Have a listen:
Highlights:
1) Western Financial Crises or Imperialist Agrarian Crises?:
--First, note that we should avoid being crude/sectarian. I’m not setting up a bipolar “either or� scenario here, as clearly both factors are present and interact with each other. I am merely contrasting the two to demonstrate the overwhelming bias that one perspective enjoys in both mainstream and alternative economics.
--(Western) Economics� conception of economic crises revolve around Western Finance:
a) Great Depression:
--Economics� focus is on the 1929 Great Crash of Wall Street, as well as the preceding “Roaring Twenties� (1920s) of mass consumer industrial production and financial speculation.
--Utsa instead focuses on agricultural production, i.e. food and certain primary commodities (raw material inputs to industry; Utsa seems less focused on energy here). WWI disrupted European agriculture, resulting in an expansion of agricultural output outside Europe. By post-WWI recovery, there was agricultural overproduction relative to demand, resulting in a severe and prolonged fall in global agricultural prices starting in 1924-25. This disrupted the trade balances of exporters; the pre-Keynesian economic response was national austerity. The resulting global demand downward spiral hit late-industrializing Germany/Italy/Japan, who (typical for capitalist crises) reacted with fascism: military production to revive demand and expansionism to seize raw materials.
--Next steps: synthesize Michael Hudson’s geopolitical economy (mostly starting from Western perspectives, Super Imperialism: The Origin and Fundamentals of U.S. World Dominance and Trade, Development and Foreign Debt) with the Patnaiks' Global South version (for their magnum opus, see Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History, and the Present).
b) Neoliberalism:
--Economics focuses on the Western stagflation crisis (unemployment + inflation) and generally blame this on labour unions and social welfare spending. Those who actually consider reality focus on the geopolitics of US’s post-WWII Bretton Woods global plan, and how it was disrupted by US genocidal war spendings in Korea and Vietnam (Hudson's aforementioned Super Imperialism and Varoufakis' The Global Minotaur: America, the True Origins of the Financial Crisis and the Future of the World Economy).
--The bridge to Global South perspectives starts with the 1973 and 1979 Oil Shocks. Note: Hudson contextualizes the Oil Shocks with a prior grain embargo by the US quadrupling grain prices (I’ll have to dig on this and how it relates with the mainstream rendition of the “Great Grain Robbery� of 1972 from USSR purchasing US grain).
--The broader Global South context is decolonization in the 1950-60s, thus de-linking of Global South developmental states away from global capitalism’s imperialist Finance/trade dependency in order to build national food sovereignty. Western “Leftists� with their heads in the clouds of Capitalist Realism: Is There No Alternative? cannot seem to empathize with this period of social change and imagination: The Darker Nations: A People's History of the Third World.
--This national de-linking and internationalist decolonization (symbolized by the push for the New International Economic Order, NIEO, to challenge colonial-era commodity pricing, finance, and technologies) was of course an existential threat to global capitalism, which responded by unleashing Finance (“Financialization�; Wall Street had been regulated after the Great Crash and during the post-WWII “Golden Age� after all) and reviving imperialist onslaughts (IMF/World Bank “Structural Adjustment Programs�). Note: Hudson stresses the US/World Bank global plan is for the US to control the global food supply (i.e. food staples) with its intensive industrial + heavily-subsidized agriculture, while the Global South exports cash crops.
c) Today’s Late-Neoliberalism:
--Since “Neoliberalism� unleashed Wall Street, there has been much to say on Financial crises (including 2008). Utsa considers the growing demand for Global South agriculture via air-freighting of perishable products alongside Neoliberalism’s destruction of postcolonial states� food sovereignty policies. Ex. India’s infamous farmer suicides starting from Neoliberal onslaughts in the 1990s, where peasant farmers must now contend with volatile global food prices (including Financial speculation), multinational corporate expansion and financial rent-seeking, all without the developmental state’s protection.
2) Western Agricultural Revolution or Free Trade Imperialism?:
--Utsa challenges the nation-by-nation narratives (which conveniently obscures imperialism) where the West supposedly went through the Industrial Revolution thanks to first completing an Agricultural Revolution into capitalist agriculture, thus generating the surpluses required for industrial inputs and wage-income consumer demands.
--Utsa rejects W. Arthur Lewis� narrative comparing Great Britain’s supposedly superior agricultural productivity by pointing out the time variable is omitted. Western Europe has 1 growing season vs. the tropical Global South’s 2-3 crops in a year. Medieval Europe was barren even for elites compared to tropical biodiversity. Indeed, the period of intense European industrialization was marked by domestic bread riots, demonstrating the lack of a successful “Agricultural Revolution� and the reliance on Ireland and tropical colonies.
--Utsa rejects Ricardo’s “Comparative Advantage� (where both countries can benefit from trade if they specialize on what is most cost-efficient for themselves, even if one country is more cost-efficient in producing both goods), the centerpiece of Classical trade theory (and adopted by Neoclassical); the material fallacy made is that both countries can produce all goods and simply chooses the most cost-efficient option. This is convenient for free trade imperialism in convincing the Global South (rich in biodiversity) that it is they who are poor and must specialize in exporting exotic cash crops to keep Global North supermarkets well-stocked for all seasons (not to mention crucial industrial inputs), giving up their food sovereignty and relying on the Global North’s heavily industrialized/subsidized agriculture for food staples (grain)!
--A final myth obscuring increased poverty in the Global South is the idea that a decline in cereal crop output is a good sign showing progress in the modernization of diets (more meat/dairy). Meat/dairy are actually a huge drain on food/energy inputs as they require significant cereal crop as livestock feed, diverting this from direct consumption.
Next Steps:
--Part of this book’s appeal is its concise (96 pages) presentation of systemic concepts. Thus, much is missing; I’ve tried to fill in some key contextual points above to demonstrate just how much contrast is created with this anti-imperialist paradigm.
--Note: Sam Moyo wrote the second (smaller) half of the book, with African examples to match Utsa’s economic framework (with more focus on land tenure property relations). Moyo’s style is a bit closer to a history textbook (more places/names rather than economic structures) reminiscent of How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, which I personally find less revelatory (esp. applied to an entire continent in 20 pages).
--Related topics that require many more pages to unpack:
1) Green Revolution: I know Vandana Shiva’s critiques are popular here, but I’m looking for more systems-level critiques. I believe Michael Perelman did his PhD on this: Farming For Profit In A Hungry World: Capital And The Crisis In Agriculture. The critique in A People’s Green New Deal is very compelling.
2) Famines: along with “gulags�, this is the popular fear-mongering against “socialism�. Here, Utsa is crucial as she both details the greatest famine conveniently ignored by the West (Bengal Famine of 1943), and challenges the famine research on communist China even beyond “Nobel� Economics Prize winner Amartya Sen and Drèze’s famous comparison of hunger in communist China vs. capitalist India in Hunger and Public Action (I review both Utsa’s critique and Sen/Drèze in this linked review).
3) Capitalism and Imperialism, mapping out the structural phases throughout history, where Utsa is joined by Prabhat Patnaik:
-overview: The Veins of the South Are Still Open: Debates Around the Imperialism of Our Time
-theory (+ debate with Harvey!): A Theory of Imperialism
-theory + history: Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History, and the Present
Sign into Å·±¦ÓéÀÖ to see if any of your friends have read
The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era.
Sign In »
Quotes Kevin Liked

“Despite all technical change in the advanced countries, to this day India, with a much smaller cultivated area than the US, produces annually a larger total tonnage of cereals, root crops, oil crops, sugar crops, fruits and vegetables. The precise figures are 858 million tonnes in India and 676 million tonnes in the US in 2007, the latest year for which the data from the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organisation is available.
As for China, its even more intensive cultivation, developed over centuries, and consequent high land productivity were legendary; Britain’s agricultural yields at that time, properly measured over the same production period, were pathetic in comparison. By 2007 China produced 1,308 million tonnes from an area substantially less than that of India and of the US.”
― The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era: Primitive Accumulation and the Peasantry
As for China, its even more intensive cultivation, developed over centuries, and consequent high land productivity were legendary; Britain’s agricultural yields at that time, properly measured over the same production period, were pathetic in comparison. By 2007 China produced 1,308 million tonnes from an area substantially less than that of India and of the US.”
― The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era: Primitive Accumulation and the Peasantry

“Yet history tells us that a deep financial and economic crisis has never occurred without a prior agrarian crisis, which tends to last even after the financial crisis abates. Consider the great depression of the inter-war period: it started not in 1929 as the conventional dating would have it, but years earlier from 1924â€�25 when global primary product prices started steadily falling. The reasons for this, in turn, were tied up with the dislocation of production in the belligerent countries during the war of inter-imperialist rivalry, the First World War of 1914â€�18. With the sharp decline in agricultural output in war-torn Europe there was expansion in agricultural output elsewhere which, with European recovery after the war, meant over-production relative to the lagging growth of mass incomes and of demand in the countries concerned. The downward pressure on global agricultural prices was so severe and prolonged that it led to the trade balances of major producing countries going into the red.”
― The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era: Primitive Accumulation and the Peasantry
― The Agrarian Question in the Neoliberal Era: Primitive Accumulation and the Peasantry
Reading Progress
January 6, 2019
– Shelved
December 12, 2021
–
Started Reading
December 17, 2021
–
Finished Reading
Comments Showing 1-6 of 6 (6 new)
date
newest »

message 1:
by
Vince
(new)
Jan 02, 2022 07:11AM

reply
|
flag

Cheers Vince, it's great to hear when someone makes use of these reviews ! Keep me posted on what you are exploring and anything you want to discuss :)


My pleasure, Kosta! Took me way too long relative to the time spent; we can't have that! This review is of Utsa Patnaik (more history-based); for summary of Prabhat Patnaik (more theory-based) I've summarized in a review of "The Veins of the South Are Still Open: Debates Around the Imperialism of Our Time" :)

If we survey the history of reactions to capitalist crises, fascism economically can be seen as an early innovation of Military Keynesianism. In other words, state spending as opposed to austerity, to temporarily revive demand given capitalist pessimism. So, fascism in terms of state-driven domestic demand may not have been the "typical" reaction until the birth of Military Keynesianism, although outward expansionism was typical for both colonialism (raw materials, cheap labor, military conquest) and settler colonialism (release the pressure of surplus labor).

"who (typical for capitalist crises) reacted with fascism":
--that was indeed poorly phrased as I was thinking of Césaire's Discourse on Colonialism (i.e. fascism is colonial practices coming home to Europe/West) rather than a precise political economic function of crisis management (ex. Michael Parenti's "rational fascism").
"pre-Keynesian economic response was national austerity":
--I'd like to update this, currently sorting through the messy The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time which has an amazing thesis: looking at the history of capitalism from the framework of the contestation between:
(a) utopian ideal of market forces esp. for the fictitous commodities of labour/land/money and
(b) protectionism so such market forces do not destroy labour/land/money.
--Thus, there were some interesting early examples of crises (Enclosures, Industrial Revolution) and crisis management (ex. Speenhamland poor relief, Poor Law reforms) during capitalism's infancy in England.